Thursday, February 6, 2025

Perceptions V

 

Big Boss Man

Well, I'm gonna get me a boss man, one gonna treat me right
Work hard in the day time, rest easy at night
Big boss man, can't you hear me when I call?
Well, you ain't so big, you're just tall, that's all

You ain’t better, you’re just bigger, that’s all.

“All that glitters is not gold” and “All that is gold does not glitter”. And just because something is bigger does not mean that it is better. Toddlers are often asked to choose between a nickel and a dime. If a toddler does not understand the value of each coin, that toddler might pick the nickel because it is bigger.

Similarly in viewing laminar/uncongested/orderly flow versus turbulent/chaotic/congested flow, the chaotic flow may appear to be bigger but that does NOT mean that it is better. It may appear that the chaotic range is 5 times the size of the orderly range, but that does NOT mean that order is 1/6 the value of chaos. In fact there are three outcomes, win, loss and TIE and that does not change. If you are perceiving more of the observable outcomes, then you should be perceiving less of the unobservable outcomes ( if you could indeed perceive them). The two dimensional odds of a win or a loss are only 50% because in a two dimensional space 50% of the surface can be perceived. But that 50% is 2/3 of the outcomes. If orderly range is 5 times the size of chaotic range, that may only be because while the dimensions are two and the surface is hyperbolic, not flat. What is being perceived as 5/6 would continue to be 2./3 on a flat surface. So the fact that the orderly observable is 5 times the size of the flat domain may only indicate that it is being perceived as 5 times the size, not that it IS 5 times the size.

In fact the unobservable ties, if they could be observed, would be perceived as 20% when they should be 33 1/3%. Thus while the observable percentage is larger, the unobservable percentage is smaller. If the mirrored but observable ties are larger, regardless of the perception that the total with unobservable wins and losses should also be larger. The median percentage of observable is .5, but it would be perceived as .6. If this is half of a half a period, then the full half period would be perceived as 120% of the actual half period. It is not bigger; it is merely PERCEIVED as being bigger. If the surface is curved, then the objects in the mirror may appear larger (or smaller) than they actually are. While passenger side view mirrors on automobile often come with this warning, it would be wise to remember this for any curved surface. Don’t ever confuse perceptions with an absolute. Don’t ever confuse bigger with better. Choose the gold not the glitter.

Wednesday, February 5, 2025

Ties III

 

Step To The Rear

Will everyone here kindly step to the rear And let a winner lead the way Here's where we separate The notes from the noise The men from the boys The rose from the poison ivy.

But what about Ties!

The outcome of every game is NOT win or lose. It is win, lose, OR TIE. Because humans do not like ties, the rules of most games may employ elaborate methods to break ties: overtime, extra innings, shoot outs, sudden death, winning by an advantage, etc.  To entice players into fair games that could end in a tie even when one player has a clear advantage over the other player, handicaps, ratings, point spreads, etc. are maintained by an impartial overseer. 

All of this is to say that ties are statistically probable and are important. But what if we could not see those ties? What if in reality wins and losses were observable but ties were not observable? What if what is perceived as ties are only the observable portion of a mirror of the original game. But a mirror game does not have to begin at the same point. Its mirror ties only have to be equal to the observable games wins and losses. That then means that the unobservable wins and losses of that mirror game also have to be equal to the ties of the observable game. If wins and losses are equally probable as ties, then this is an inevitable outcome. If wins, loses, and ties are all equally likely then each should occur 33 and 1/3% of the time. That means the unobserved ties should be equal to the total of observable wins and losses. And if the observable wins and losses are equal to the observable but mirror ties, then the mirror game has to be twice the size of the original game. And the dividing line between observable wins and losses and observable but mirror ties should occur at 2/3, 66 2/3 % of the total outcomes. This also means that the intersection point of the original game and its mirror must occur exactly at 50% of all games. If it occurs at a different point, for the observer to perceive observable wins and losses to be equal to the observable mirror ties then it may be necessary for a different surface than the normal Euclidean surface to be used.

There are three surface types as indicated by their curvature: Spherical, Flat (Euclidean); and Hyperbolic. The limit of an outcome on a spherical surface is the same as the outcome on a flat surface if the size of the Radius of the Sphere is large enough. This is because of the identity 1=cos2+sin2. However the limit on a hyperbolic surface will NOT be the same as that of a flat surface because of the identity 1=cosh2-sinh2. Thus if the starting points of the mirrored game and the original game are not identical, their intersection will not occur at the median of each,  and if the area above the intersection appears smaller, then it is most probably a hyperbolic surface. 

If the surface is flat then the observable perception of a 3-D object on that surface is 50%. And thus 50% is unobservable. You can infer the characteristics of the unboreable portion of the object, but you can NOT observe them. On a hyperbolic surface, the perception would be different. Thus while on a spherical or flat surface the perception might be that the original game is twice the size of the original game. If the intersection is NOT at 50%, the mirror of the original game would be perceived as 5/6 of the original game, (or its additive, and symmetric, inverse 1/6), not 2/3, (or 1/3). The fact that there are observable ties that are a mirror of unobservable wins and losses must lead to the conclusion that the intersection is occurring on a hyperbolic surface and the intersection is perceived to be at 5/6, not 2/3. This is only because it is also being perceived from hyperbolic surface. This has an implication on behavior that will be explored in the next blog post.

 

 

 

 

Wednesday, January 29, 2025

Perceptions IV

 

You’ve Got to Hide Your Love ( Beach Boys version)

Hey! Somebody hid my teeth away (Just call that number...) Hey! Somebody hid my teeth away (Everly Brothers.) (Hey!) (What's the best Everly Brothers song? Besides, ah...) (Go.) ("Bird Dog.") (Who's gonna fool with it?) (You're gonna fool with it. You and me.) (You shouldn't fool with an Everly Brothers song--you should do it right.)

You shouldn’t fool with ANYthing, just do it right!

Trying to make inferences from existing trends is good. But remember they are only inferences. Don’t expect those inferences to be perfect, and be prepared to change them and NOT fall in love with your inferences.  Not only your inferences, but the inferences that others make should also be questioned. What seems to be consistent with your inferences might only be a foolish consistency and remember what Emerson said about foolish consistencies.

For example the trend inferred of perceiving the absolute. The absolute  will be perceived from a frame of reference. Our frame of reference is not absolute so we can’t expect our perception of the absolute to be absolutely correct. Just because someone else’s perception seems to be close to ours, that does not confirm ours.

Our perception of the absolute can be a System Perspective, that the perceived slope of the absolute is all that is important. It can also be a User Perspective, that the starting point of the absolute is all that is important. It can be that  the perceived starting point AND the perceived slope are both important. Thus is called a Nash Equilibrium after mathematician John Nash.

The perception of the only the slope which is the System Optimal, SO, parameter trended to the perceived starting point is close to the User Optimal, UO,  parameters. The parameters of the Nash Equilibrium, NE, are not close to either those of the SO or UO. But the parameters of the Nash Equilibrium match better to the perception of the absolute than either that of the System or User Optimals.



The blue dots and lines are User Optimals, UO. The red dots and lines are the System Optimals, SO. The brown dots and lines are Nash Equilibriums, NE. Despite the fact that the UO and SO parameters are close together at the left side of this graph, the parameters of the Nash Equilibrium are closer to  both the perceptions of the absolute at both the Left, and Right sides of the graph, despite being farther away from the trend of either UO or SO parameters. It is more important to be consistent with the perception of the absolute than it is to be consistent with the perception of others. Don’t be fooled.

 

Friday, January 24, 2025

It's a secret

 

Give a Little Whistle

Take the strait and narrow path And if you start to slide Give a little whistle Give a little whistle And always let your conscience be your guide.

And doesn’t voting your conscience mean a secret ballot?

To eliminate bullying, and/or voter intimidation, votes by ballot are secret. There is a reason for this secrecy. Then voters can NOT be subject to retaliation on how they voted in their ballot.

The same is true for voting by senators and representatives of the people. But each of their votes is public and potentially subject to retaliation. Shouldn’t their votes of conscience also be secret? This includes votes to impeach a sitting candidate or approve a nominated candidate. Votes to  override an executive veto are already by  2/3 of both houses of Congress. Shouldn’t those votes also be secret? Votes to override a judicial action may involve a constitutional amendment which already requires more than a simple majority of states and Congress. Shouldn’t these votes also be secret. Declaring war, entering into treaties,  as well as any action that already requires a 2/3 vote should arguably be by secret vote. This also includes the ending of debate and the advancing of proposed bills to a policy vote. 

Matters of simple policy are by simple majority and there is no reason that they can not be public votes. But votes of conscience should be different. This does not require a complicated process. Elections by all of the voters are already by secret ballot. Secret votes by their representatives can be by black and white balls (hence the term blackballed). Making votes secret is merely a way to ensure that bullying and retaliation don’t interfere with your conscience being your guide.

Wednesday, January 22, 2025

Perceptions III

 

If You Could See Her

Yet when we're walking together
They sneer if I'm holding her hand
But if they could see her through my eyes
Maybe they'd all understand

I understand your objection
I grant you the problem's not small
But if you could see her through my eyes
She wouldn't look Jewish at all!

Misperception is deadly.

As individuals we can only perceive the absolute from a surface. If that surface is hyperbolic, while the absolute is zero at absolute zero, to an individual on that hyperbolic surface, the absolute would be perceived as a normal logistic, sech squared, distribution. That means that while there is an absolute zero, it is perceived as having a value of 2%. That 2% is because of the Standard Deviation, what an  engineer would call tolerance, of the absolute. Therefore what is absolute zero to the absolute is 2% to an individual observing that absolute from a hyperbolic surface.

If life begins at birth, is absolute zero, from the perspective of the absolute it has no value, but it is perceived by an individual on a hyperbolic surface as having a value of 2%. This leads to the individual to perceive that life before birth, before an absolute zero, must also have a value. It is possible therefore that the belief in fetal personhood is only because of this misperception.

Tuesday, January 21, 2025

Perceptions II

 

Life is a Highway

Life is a highway I want to ride it all night long If you're going' my way Well, I want to drive it all night long

Actually life is an “S” curve

For the first 20% of your life, you are a ward of the group. That is because while you can contribute to the group, your contribution to the group is much lower than during the next 60% of your life. In fact it is on average only 36% of the contribution during the  middle 60%. It is not until you retire, during the last 20% of an average life, that you return to the same level of contribution. During the middle 60%, your contribution to the group on average is more than 2.8 times the contribution during the first, or last, 20%. Also from a hyperbolic surface, the absolute will be perceived to contribute 2% at the beginning of life, the same amount that is perceived to be contributed at the end of the average individual’s existence. This is dictated by mathematics and the perception of an absolute from a hyperbolic surface. This absolute curve is perceived by individuals on a hyperbolic surface is a  Sigmoid or “S” curve. If this curve is approximated by three straight lines, it is as shown below. The Grey line is the absolute. The Yellow line is the perception of the absolute by an individual on a hyperbolic surface. The Blue lines are the approximation of that perception by three straight lines.




It is the perception of extending the straight line during the middle to 0% that mistakenly gives the impression that you are being an absolute, instead of perceiving an absolute. The true slope is why the initial phase change, operation, introduction, of new products/policies, is much lower than expected and a new action is often mistakenly called a “Folly”. Extending the trend at the other end is why financial bubbles burst, manias occur, and Ponzi schemes do not work. 

The parameters of the upper limit of the middle trend line is also called a Nash Equilibrium. Individuals approximating this curve might be expected to follow a normal distribution with these parameters. The upper line starts at 80% of an average lifespan. In the middle years, the slope is 280% of the slope at either tail. Trying to extend that middle curve without realizing it is a Sigmoid Curve is a common fallacy. If policies are enacted often that mistakenly assume that just because we perceive that a life has a value of 2% at  0 years, it does not mean that to an absolute it is not 0% at 0 years, The value at the upper end should also be an absolute. Trying to force the upper curve to the middle trend line is why the variance in income, income inequality, has increased.

The x- axis of the chart above is because an individual can also only perceive one half of the period of an absolute. That period is 2 π i, because it is also the period of a hyperbolic cosine, cosh(x). Therefore the half period of an absolute perceived by individuals on a hyperbolic surface is π, 3.1415…


 

 



Winning II

 

Everybody Wants To Rule The World

I can't stand this indecision
Married with a lack of vision
Everybody wants to rule the—
Say that you'll never, never, never, never need it
One headline, why believe it?
Everybody wants to rule the world

Don’t try to rule the world, the absolute has already beat you to it!

There is a difference between certainty and dominance. The absolute is certain 100% of the time. The winner, dominator, of any contest between two groups, when those groups are NOT absolute, even if the contest is normal and fair, is only certain 91% of the time. If the contest is fair, then it can be assumed that the number of false losses will be equal to, offset, the number of false wins. If the contest is NOT normal, then the number of false wins can be greater than the number of false losses, and the winner of the contest can be false and not certain.

If the contest is certain and normal, then the number in each group has to approach the absolute, infinity. Measures to decrease the numbers of any of the competing groups, such as voter suppression or discrimination, will only increase the percentage of wins which are uncertain.

If a contest is a zero-sum game, e.g. there is no growth, then the winner has an incentive to maximize false, uncertain, wins and then to destroy their opponent so that there will be no more contests with that opponent. That incentive does not exist in non-zero sum games, nor in contests where the players can not be destroyed.

If contests are fair and normal, they can still be only false wins 9% of the time. If the contest is fair and normal, the percentage of false wins should also be equal to the percentage of false losses.  Ranked choice voting for example rehabitates ballots when its winner receives only a plurality of the wins until a majority is achieved. The second place finisher of each eliminated ballot then becomes the presumptive first place finisher when ballots after the lowest first place candidate is eliminated and the ballots are recounted. This is identical with a winner being determined by total points where a first place finish is worth 3 points, a second place finish is worth 2 points, and a third pace finish is worth 1 point. That is how sports polling, selection of a list of Best restaurants, etc., or many polls are determined.

If the number of members of a group is not restricted, zero sum games are not allowed, and rank choice voting is used, then the contests can be fair and normal. The winner of that contest will be certain, true, 91% of the time. If the entry to the contest  is restricted, zero sum games are allowed, and rank choice voting is not used, a dominate win can be only because of false wins, not because of true wins.  As always, any winner whose is not an absolute can approach, but not be, an absolute.